What is the “human grid,” and why do you need it?

In an article in Aeon magazine, Michelle Nijhuis writes about her experience living in—and eventually leaving—an off-the-grid commune on Colorado’s Western slope. What drew Michelle to this lifestyle is a tantalizing proposition: “a place where [Michelle and her friends] could unplug from the electrical grid—and from a society they saw as wasteful and destructive.” At least, as someone who is concerned about climate change and about the future of the planet’s natural resources, the low-footprint lifestyle is appealing to me. But along the way, Michelle and her family discover they need—or at least want and value—some things that an unplugged, tucked-away, life cannot offer.

Michelle Nijhuis and family, from Aeon Magazine

Although Michelle states outright that she was never fully “off the grid” in economic terms (gas, clothing, some groceries came from the outside), her description of the grid sheds some light on why exactly she wanted off it in the first place. “We were a mile and a half from town, 30 miles from a Wal­mart, 70 miles from a Starbucks, and more than an hour’s drive from anything that qualified as an airport.” Thirty miles was probably barely enough space between them and the ultimate symbol of excess, corporate profits, and the demise of the proverbial main street.

After years on the commune, people start to return to the society they had left. It wasn’t for the comfortable lifestyle and Starbucks lattes, but for things that only a bigger society can provide:

“When Nancy, a chiropractor, was diagnosed with breast cancer, she moved east to be closer to her extended family and to medical care. When Marc, an architect, was struck by a neurological disorder that left him unable to walk and speak, he and his family left for a larger town with wheelchair ramps and social services.”

Medical care; public services. These are economies of goods and services that provide real value to people, and they can’t exist in isolation. I’ll admit here that these are not strictly services that live in the realm of economics. They are political: societies make decisions as a whole to provide goods like wheelchair ramps through government and regulation. But it is not a problem of democracy or lack of sympathy within the commune that prevents them from taking care of their own. It makes little sense for them to install wheelchair lifts and ramps throughout the property for the one man in a wheelchair or build a hospital for a single woman with cancer. Humans derive strength from numbers, from community, from society. The principle that allows a city to provide social services, health care, and even a social life for a young girl is not so different from the one that allows us to save and lend money through banking, protect ourselves from unforeseeable catastrophe with health insurance.

These vilified industries—banks, insurance companies—fundamentally rely on community, and they aren’t inherently bad for societyThat’s not to say they don’t have problems in their current form.  At a time of too-big-to-fail bank bailouts, corruption on Wall Street, and increasing income disparity, I am afraid people outside of the field of economics are seeing the skewed system, and thinking “this is what economics is all about.” I see people who want to eschew banking, money, and trade (This is partly why I wrote my first series, “Libertarians don’t like money, but they still use it”). They want to eschew what Nijhuis calls “the human grid.” I fear that people will remove themselves from the system, rather than change it. Because the banking system right now is messed up, the rules are too often written by those with the most money, and markets are skewed with subsidies and tax breaks in all the wrong places. If we choose to remove ourselves from it, we allow those who remain to perpetuate it. If we choose to stay, we can change it. We can recognize that the economy—the human grid—has a lot to offer, as long as we guide it wisely.

Obamacare allows monopolies in rural areas

This is one of the most important articles I’ve seen yet on the future of Obamacare: Health Care Law Fails to Lower Prices in Rural Areas.

This article addresses actual flaws in the law’s effects. (That is, it is NOT about how bad the website is, and this is why I found it worth reading.) Overall, I think Obamacare will benefit the country, but I hope we  take concerns like this seriously. Here is your vocab du jour:

Monopoly (power)!

Monopoly: A situation in which a single company or group owns all or nearly all of the market for a given type of product or service. By definition, monopoly is characterized by an absence of competition, which often results in high prices and inferior products.

As I see it, the intent of the health care exchanges to weaken insurance companies’ leverage over their customers by creating competition between insurers. If a rural county is served by only one insurer, they can exert monopoly forces over the market. That is, they can afford to jack up prices at the expense of losing a few customers. Basic economic theory tells us, essentially, that too little of a service is provided, it is provided at too high of a cost, and it is often of a lower quality.

In a market where insurance is mandated by law, the effect is worse. If there are no other alternatives (other than facing penalties), more people will sign up for health care than they would in a market in which they are free to take or leave the service. At best, it’s good for health care numbers, but economically it’s worse than a simple monopoly.

There are multiple possible solutions. One, from the article, is to provide “multistate” plans. Essentially, it is a option provided by the federal government. However, as law professor Timothy Jost points out, the multistate plans are often the same one as the county’s single insurer: “If you’ve got Blue Cross competing with Blue Cross, it doesn’t give you much competition.” So we’d need at least two insurers to compete in multistate plans to make sure there are two different companies (at least) competing in any given county, and the monopoly is actually broken up.

Why barriers to entry are dangerous.

Another possibility is the co-op (“consumer operated”). The idea is that even if the insurers don’t think the market in a rural county is big enough to be worth their while, the people living there still care a lot about how much they pay for health insurance. If they can provide it at lower cost by pooling their resources—with the help of some federal funding—consumers will choose that option and put downward pressure on prices in their market. The co-op illustrates an important point about monopolies: they can only hold on to their control of the market when other firms face barriers to entry into a market.

Whatever else Obamacare does, the online system is doing its best to eliminate barriers to entry by allowing consumers to view and sign up for plans offered by smaller providers and co-ops. In the long run, I would not expect monopolies to survive in an open market, because another corporation or a co-op would enter the market.

The question is what to do until then. I would suggest deferring the insurance mandate for single-provider counties to give them enough time to produce (at the very least) two providers. This would allow consumers to avoid getting the bad end of a monopoly deal, and may even exert downward pressure on the cost of health care until then.

Obamacare is chipping away at the power of health care and health insurance providers over their customers, but there is still much work to be done. Hopefully, we will see the value in keeping our population healthy and continue to improve it, not try and dismantle it.

Republicans treat US Government like all-you-can-eat buffet… economically speaking

  • Marginal Utility: The additional satisfaction a consumer [or society] gains from consuming one more unit of a good or service.
  • Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility: A law of economics stating that as a person [or society] increases consumption of a product – while keeping consumption of other products constant – there is a decline in the marginal utility that person derives from consuming each additional unit of that product.

I told myself I wouldn’t get into the government shutdown on this blog, but here I am. However, I promise this post is not meant to be political or an attack on Republicans—I’m trying to teach some economics here!

Finding themselves in the hotseat for the government shutdown, Republicans began passing piecemeal legislation to fund particular government programs (Some in G.O.P. Try to Pick and Choose Amid Spending Fight, New York Tmes, Oct 5). I found their choices to reveal truths about government (especially government spending) that they don’t often voice. More importantly, we have a great economic framework to describe them!

Imagine you are tasked with creating the budget for the current fiscal year to take effect as soon as the shutdown ends. It’s all up to you—but here’s the caveat: they have haven’t actually told you how much money they are going to authorize. What do you do?

If it was me, I’d make a list. Start with the federal programs that give you the most bang for your buck—the most benefit, or utility, per dollar—then work my way down. Not knowing when the money would run out, I would make sure the good ones are right at the top. What would your list look like? Maybe something like this:

  • “Fully fund the National Institutes of Health”
  • “Supplemental nutriton program for women, infants, and children”
  • “National parks”
  • “Nutrition for the impoverished”
  • “Guarantee that federal workers…will receive back pay once the government reopens”
  • “The Smithsonian Institution”
  • “Funding the V.A.”
  • “Head Start classrooms”
  • “Finance border security and enforcement”
  • “Nuclear weapons security and development”
  • “Indian education and health services”
  • “The Food and Drug Administration”
  • …continue the list…

This is basically list offered so far by House Republicans. My own list would have included “Obamacare” up there somewhere, but hey, that’s just me. So it appears that Republicans are picking and choosing from last year’s budget like it was an all-you-can-eat buffet, but the analogy gets better. Finding definitions to introduce the concepts in this post, I noticed Investopedia’s follow-up explanation for the Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility:

“Say you go to a buffet and the first plate of food you eat is very good. On a scale of ten you would give it a ten. Now your hunger has been somewhat tamed, but you get another full plate of food. Since you’re not as hungry, your enjoyment rates at a seven at best. Most people would stop before their utility drops even more, but say you go back to eat a third full plate of food and your utility drops even more to a three. If you kept eating, you would eventually reach a point at which your eating makes you sick, providing dissatisfaction, or ‘dis-utility’.”

That mouse enjoys the last cookie way less than the first.

That mouse enjoys the last cookie way less than the first.

But like a buffet, however, you’re not just glopping generic “government spending food” onto your budget plate. You pick your favorite foods first, and fill the white space on your plate with the next-best choices. As you fill your plate, the marginal utility of each item decreases. Why? Because you’ve already picked the best ones! In Congress, it’s obviously not that simple. Politics and differing opinion of which programs are actually valuable means some good programs face cuts, while other less useful pet projects get funded.

So the Republicans have picked made their “best” picks, and I find it fascinating that they chose many programs that they were trying to defund weeks earlier. I think the shutdown forced them to come face to face with their anti-“big government” platform to see what happens when these institutions aren’t in place. If there’s a silver lining in the shutdown, it is that it served as a reality-check for lawmakers to see what government services people actually rely on and care about. To be clear, I don’t think this is a responsible way to finance the government. But I do think it is a positive way to start conceptualizing how the government provides services to the public, and we need to keep telling Congress to line up the programs it funds with the benefit they give to the country.

I have to say, I can sympathize with Republicans when it comes to the inefficiencies of government bureaucracy. Perhaps our tax dollars could be better spend. But I think it is better than the alternative, and I find it hard to make the case that we need less spending when so many quality programs run on a shoestring budget and there is so much more room for investment in public goods (top of my personal “marginal utility” list: public education, modern public transportation, fixing failing bridges and infrastructure…). If there is room for common ground between the poles of the political spectrum, I think it lies in closer consideration of the actual utility of government programs, not sweeping statements about government spending. If we think critically about the specific services provided by the government, I think we’ll all have a better idea of just how big the government should be.

Libertarians don’t like money, but they still use it (Part 3)

Store of Value

Store of value: an item that people can use to transfer purchasing power from the present to the future

Thanks for adventuring with me one last time to the Porcupine Freedom Festival. If I traded a piece of silver to a man selling omelettes, it’s important that he will be able to use that piece of silver as a medium of exchange tomorrow, or a year from now—and that it will hold its value.

With that in mind, perhaps gold and silver do best at the function of store of value. People have often turned to gold as a commodity that will hold its value, especially in the face of uncertain economic times. Check out what you get when you Google “store of value” for images:

This is what comes up when you Google image search for "store of value." A lot of gold.

This is what comes up when you Google image search for “store of value.” A lot of gold.

But like any other investment, it’s a bet on a particular commodity or financial instrument. Most people who buy gold do so as a small part of a greater diverse portfolio. For a porcupine libertarian, they’re putting it all on gold. “It’s not if,” they say, “but when” the US Dollar crashes, that they will be invested in the moneys that will never lose their value: gold, silver, and other precious metals.

Another iPhone app for the price of gold. Let’s hope you don’t need to buy groceries at the Porcupine Freedom Festival this week, because you just lost a lot of your purchasing power!

On a day-to-day basis, however, gold doesn’t hold up quite as well. As I mentioned last time, the price of precious metals can be highly volatile. Look what happened when Richard went to buy his omelette after exchanging his dollars for silver:

“I actually got a great deal on that omelette. They valued silver at a higher price than I bought it at, 10 minutes later! I made a profit!”

This is all well and good for Richard, but not so good the maker of the omelette. Plus, it could have gone the other way just as easily if the price of silver had dropped.

A property of money that serves the store of value function well is price stability. Store of value doesn’t just refer to long-term investments, but the ability to take income and make purchases with it in the short term. Even though candy bars from a vending machine were 75¢ when I was little and are now $1.25 due to inflation, the price didn’t jump around much day-to-day.

Stability makes economic decisions easier because you don’t have to worry about losing a large amount of your purchasing power (oops! another term! I’ll have to come back to this another day) because of a random fluctuation in the value of your money. Even though their gold and silver fulfills the role of money in their “barter” economy, they might be better off using something else… like the dollar.

Of course, if they’re right, I’m going to end up holding a lot of useless paper.

Money is everywhere.

The point of this series was not to get political or ridicule libertarians for sticking with the gold standard. Instead, it is to understand money as an concept beyond little pieces of paper that the government prints out and forces upon its citizens. As a matter of fact, money is often spontaneously created by people in a society—and this is more or less what we observed at the Porcupine Freedom Festival. The porcupines adopted commodities, mostly gold and silver, as their currency. Just about everyone uses money in some form or another, including the people who say they reject it. While gold and silver fulfilled the function medium of exchange fairly well, it didn’t do so well for the others. In my next segment, I’d like to talk about what makes good money—and see how “Libertarian money” stacks up.

Link

Libertarians don’t like money, but they sure do act like it (Part 1)

When I explain why I chose economics as my area of study, I often find myself explaining what it isn’t. I don’t study business. I don’t study accounting. I don’t study finance. And these things aren’t the same as “money.” I want to start the blog by examining money precisely because it is misunderstood. Money is fundamental to economics, but economics is about much more than money.

I want to use Planet Money’s podcast “Libertarian Summer Camp” as the springboard for this post, where reporter Robert Smith ventures to what I can only imagine is the most anti-government festival in America, the Porcupine Freedom Festial. Libertarians believe in independence and limited government intervention (to varying degrees, of course), and the most fervent brand of libertarianism can be found at the Porcupine Freedom Festival. They call themselves “porcupines.”

I have to admit, there are some instances where I sympathize with with these guys—government regulations can be onerous and over-the-top in ways that no benevolent economist dictator would ever dream of. However, there was one aspect of their beliefs that stuck out like a sore thumb: these people eschew money. I hope by the end of this three-part series you will understand why this seemed so strange to me.

And so I’d like to explain the three functions of money using as my example a group of people who insist they don’t use it. I promised to make economic concepts relatable, but I want to start with the textbook definition:

The three functions of money

The author wearing a handsome George Washington t-shirt made out of a one dollar Federal Reserve Note.

The author wearing a handsome George Washington t-shirt made out of a one dollar Federal Reserve Note.

(from notoriously conservative economist Gregory Mankiw’s “Principles of Macroeconomics”, 2012)

  1. Medium of exchange: an item that buyers give to sellers when they want to purchase goods and services
  2. Unit of account: the yardstick people use to post prices and record debts
  3. Store of value: an item that people can use to transfer purchasing power from the present to the future

If you haven’t done so already, now would be a good time to give the podcast a listen. Even the first few minutes would be helpful to understand what we’re talking about.

Medium of Exchange

This is probably the first thing that comes to mind when you think of money. I give you money, you give me food or clothing or something else I want. Ask a “porcupine” what they use as a medium of exchange, and they’ll probably say they don’t have one:

“They say you are not ‘buying’ something with silver, you are trading something of value—silver—for something else of value.”

That is, they’ll say it’s a barter economy. People do barter goods and services directly, but more frequently they trade in gold and silver. And because sellers commonly accept gold and silver, we consider them exchange media. Even if the seller doesn’t particularly want some precious metal to own and use himself, he will accept it because he can trade it for something else he does want. This particular kind of money is called commodity money, which is defined by having intrinsic value (as opposed to fiat money like our dollar bills, which intrinsically are only useful making little origami t-shirts, see photo). The festival has a particularly interesting way of dealing with their commodity money:

“Ron…basically shaves off pieces of metal—he buys them from a jewelry supplier—and then he laminates them. He takes the little tiny strips of metal, and he has an office laminator, and he makes something like the size of a credit card.”

If you weren’t convinced already, these are money. They are designed for exchange value (the ability to trade them for something else), rather than use value (any direct use , enjoyment or utility gained from owning the money). It would be difficult to really make use out of your gold and silver cards, but you could if you really wanted to.

So far, we have seen our porcupines use a medium of exchange. Next time, we’ll explore their unit of account. I listened to this podcast on a run the other day, and I had to stop to laugh. As an economist, I found it hilarious. I hope you will too.

Welcome to Opportunity Science.

I named this blog for one of the most basic and important concepts in economics: opportunity cost. But I wanted to flip that notion on its head. It’s not just a cost, but literally an opportunity. Instead of the “dismal science,” let’s think of it as the science of opportunity.

Supply & Demand

An excellent example of the kind of economic literacy this blog aims to promote. Infographic by Max Henkels.

The goal of this blog is multifaceted. First, I want to make basic economic principles and concepts applicable in areas you care about. This discipline has much to offer in environmental and social situations in ways many people are unaware.

Second, I want to make these concepts fun and allow you to recognize them in everyday life. In a sense, every decision you make is an economic one, and I want to shed some light on the tools economics has to offer. If you don’t already, check out NPR’s Planet Money podcast, which does a great job of this already. I will be using some of their podcasts as starting points.

Last, I want to offer news commentary with an economic spin. Usually my thoughts end up on facebook as a two-sentence blip, and I want to have a space to explore them more thoroughly. I will be pulling largely from the New York times, and using what I see in the news as fodder for my first two goals.

I welcome questions, respectful debate, and suggestions for posts. Welcome to Opportunity Science.